Behavioural Finance Limits To Arbitrage
Behavioral Finance: Limits to Arbitrage
Traditional finance theory posits that rational investors exploit mispricings in the market, driving prices towards their intrinsic values. This process, known as arbitrage, ensures market efficiency. However, behavioral finance recognizes that psychological biases and market frictions can limit arbitrage, allowing mispricings to persist.
One significant limit is fundamental risk. Even if an asset is clearly undervalued, negative news or events related to the asset's underlying business can erode its value before the arbitrageur can profit. This risk is particularly acute in the short term, forcing arbitrageurs to take a long-term view, which may not always be feasible due to capital constraints.
Noise trader risk is another crucial impediment. Noise traders, driven by emotions and irrational beliefs, can push prices further away from fundamental value, creating losses for arbitrageurs. This "irrational exuberance" or "irrational pessimism" can be sustained for extended periods, making it difficult for rational investors to predict when prices will revert to their intrinsic values. If noise traders drive prices up, short-selling arbitrageurs are vulnerable to margin calls, potentially forcing them to close their positions at a loss before the mispricing corrects. This risk is exacerbated by feedback loops where noise traders amplify each other's actions.
Implementation costs significantly limit arbitrage. Short-selling, often necessary to profit from overvalued assets, incurs costs such as borrowing fees, search costs for available shares, and potential legal restrictions. These costs reduce the profitability of arbitrage opportunities, making them less attractive. Furthermore, transaction costs, such as brokerage commissions and bid-ask spreads, further erode potential profits. These costs can be particularly burdensome for smaller arbitrageurs with limited capital.
Agency problems also play a role. Portfolio managers, who typically manage other people's money, are often evaluated on short-term performance. They may be reluctant to take positions that, while fundamentally sound, could lead to short-term losses due to noise trader risk. Furthermore, principal-agent problems can lead to career risk aversion, where managers prioritize job security over maximizing returns, potentially missing out on profitable but risky arbitrage opportunities.
Model risk arises from relying on models to determine intrinsic value. If the model is flawed or based on incorrect assumptions, it can lead to inaccurate valuations and failed arbitrage attempts. The complexity of modern financial markets, coupled with the inherent uncertainty in forecasting future events, makes model risk a significant concern.
In conclusion, while arbitrage plays a crucial role in promoting market efficiency, behavioral biases and market frictions create significant limits to its effectiveness. Fundamental risk, noise trader risk, implementation costs, agency problems, and model risk all contribute to the persistence of mispricings in financial markets, highlighting the importance of understanding behavioral finance principles.